IB Economics SL

Demand & Supply, Equilibrium | Microeconomics Part I | IB Economics SL

Unit 2: Microeconomics Part I - Demand, Supply & Equilibrium

Welcome to the Core of Microeconomics! This unit explores the fundamental forces that drive market economies: demand and supply. You'll learn how these forces interact to determine prices, allocate resources, and create market equilibrium. Understanding demand and supply is essential for analyzing virtually every microeconomic issue you'll encounter in IB Economics.

1. The Law of Demand

The Law of Demand: As the price of a good or service increases, the quantity demanded decreases, ceteris paribus (all other factors remaining constant). Conversely, as price decreases, quantity demanded increases.

This creates an inverse (negative) relationship between price and quantity demanded.
Mathematical Representation: \[ P \uparrow \Rightarrow Q_d \downarrow \] \[ P \downarrow \Rightarrow Q_d \uparrow \]

Why Does the Law of Demand Hold?

The law of demand is based on three key economic principles:

1. The Substitution Effect

When the price of a good increases, consumers substitute it with relatively cheaper alternatives. When price decreases, consumers buy more of that good instead of alternatives.

Example: If coffee prices rise, consumers may switch to tea. If coffee prices fall, consumers buy more coffee instead of tea.

2. The Income Effect

When the price of a good increases, consumers' real purchasing power (real income) decreases, so they buy less. When price decreases, real income effectively increases, allowing consumers to buy more.

Example: If gasoline prices double, your $100 buys less gas, reducing your real income and forcing you to purchase less.

3. The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility

As consumers consume more units of a good, each additional unit provides less satisfaction (utility). Therefore, consumers are only willing to buy additional units at lower prices.

Example: Your first slice of pizza provides great satisfaction, but the fifth slice provides much less. You'd only buy that fifth slice if the price were lower.

The Demand Curve

Demand Curve: A graphical representation showing the relationship between price and quantity demanded. It slopes downward from left to right, reflecting the inverse relationship described by the law of demand.
📊 Demand Curve Diagram: Price (P) on vertical axis, Quantity Demanded (Qd) on horizontal axis. The curve slopes downward from top-left to bottom-right, labeled "D".

Demand vs. Quantity Demanded

Critical Distinction:
  • Change in Quantity Demanded: Movement ALONG the demand curve caused by a change in PRICE only
  • Change in Demand: SHIFT of the entire demand curve caused by changes in NON-PRICE determinants

2. Determinants of Demand (Non-Price Factors)

Several factors can shift the entire demand curve to the right (increase in demand) or left (decrease in demand):

1. Income

Normal Goods: Demand increases when income increases (positive relationship)
Example: Organic food, branded clothing, restaurant meals

Inferior Goods: Demand decreases when income increases (negative relationship)
Example: Instant noodles, public transportation (for some), second-hand goods
Normal Goods: \( \text{Income} \uparrow \Rightarrow \text{Demand} \uparrow \)
Inferior Goods: \( \text{Income} \uparrow \Rightarrow \text{Demand} \downarrow \)

2. Price of Related Goods

Substitute Goods: Goods that can replace each other in consumption
  • If the price of Good A (substitute) increases, demand for Good B increases
  • Examples: Butter and margarine, Coca-Cola and Pepsi, chicken and beef

\( P_{\text{substitute}} \uparrow \Rightarrow D_{\text{good}} \uparrow \)

Complementary Goods: Goods consumed together
  • If the price of Good A (complement) increases, demand for Good B decreases
  • Examples: Cars and gasoline, coffee and sugar, smartphones and apps

\( P_{\text{complement}} \uparrow \Rightarrow D_{\text{good}} \downarrow \)

3. Tastes and Preferences

  • Favorable change: Advertising campaigns, fashion trends, health awareness → Demand increases
  • Unfavorable change: Negative publicity, health warnings, changing trends → Demand decreases
Real-World Example: Growing health consciousness has increased demand for organic foods and gym memberships while decreasing demand for sugary drinks and fast food (in many markets).

4. Consumer Expectations

  • Expected future price increase: Current demand increases (buy now before price rises)
  • Expected future price decrease: Current demand decreases (wait for lower prices)
  • Expected income increase: Current demand may increase (especially for durables)

5. Number of Consumers

  • Population increase: Market demand increases
  • Demographics: Aging population increases demand for healthcare
  • Market expansion: More buyers enter the market → demand increases

Summary Table: Determinants of Demand

DeterminantChangeEffect on DemandCurve Shift
Income (Normal Good)IncreasesIncreasesRight
Income (Inferior Good)IncreasesDecreasesLeft
Price of SubstituteIncreasesIncreasesRight
Price of ComplementIncreasesDecreasesLeft
Favorable TastesChange occursIncreasesRight
Expected Future PriceExpected to riseIncreases nowRight
Number of ConsumersIncreasesIncreasesRight

3. The Law of Supply

The Law of Supply: As the price of a good or service increases, the quantity supplied increases, ceteris paribus. Conversely, as price decreases, quantity supplied decreases.

This creates a direct (positive) relationship between price and quantity supplied.
Mathematical Representation: \[ P \uparrow \Rightarrow Q_s \uparrow \] \[ P \downarrow \Rightarrow Q_s \downarrow \]

Why Does the Law of Supply Hold?

1. Profit Motive

Higher prices provide greater profit potential, incentivizing producers to increase production. Lower prices reduce profit margins, making production less attractive.

2. Increasing Marginal Costs

As production increases, marginal costs typically rise due to diminishing returns and capacity constraints. Higher prices are needed to cover these increasing costs and justify expanded production.

3. New Entrants

Higher prices attract new firms to enter the market, increasing total market supply. Lower prices may force some firms to exit.

The Supply Curve

Supply Curve: A graphical representation showing the relationship between price and quantity supplied. It slopes upward from left to right, reflecting the positive relationship described by the law of supply.
📊 Supply Curve Diagram: Price (P) on vertical axis, Quantity Supplied (Qs) on horizontal axis. The curve slopes upward from bottom-left to top-right, labeled "S".

Supply vs. Quantity Supplied

Critical Distinction:
  • Change in Quantity Supplied: Movement ALONG the supply curve caused by a change in PRICE only
  • Change in Supply: SHIFT of the entire supply curve caused by changes in NON-PRICE determinants

4. Determinants of Supply (Non-Price Factors)

Several factors can shift the entire supply curve to the right (increase in supply) or left (decrease in supply):

1. Costs of Production

Production costs include wages, raw materials, rent, utilities, and other inputs:

  • Costs increase: Supply decreases (shift left) - less profitable to produce
  • Costs decrease: Supply increases (shift right) - more profitable to produce
\[ \text{Production Costs} \uparrow \Rightarrow \text{Supply} \downarrow \] \[ \text{Production Costs} \downarrow \Rightarrow \text{Supply} \uparrow \]
Example: Rising oil prices increase transportation and production costs for many goods, shifting supply curves left. Alternatively, falling steel prices reduce costs for automobile manufacturers, shifting supply right.

2. Technology

  • Technological improvements: Increase productivity and reduce per-unit costs → Supply increases
  • Examples: Automation, better machinery, improved production processes
Example: 3D printing technology has increased supply in manufacturing. Agricultural innovations like drought-resistant crops increase food supply.

3. Prices of Related Goods in Production

Competitive Supply (Substitutes in Production):

Goods that can be produced using the same resources

  • If profit from Good A increases, producers switch resources from Good B to Good A
  • Supply of Good B decreases
  • Example: A farmer can grow wheat or corn. If wheat prices rise, the farmer allocates more land to wheat, reducing corn supply
Joint Supply (Complementary in Production):

Goods produced together from the same process

  • Increased production of Good A automatically increases supply of Good B
  • Examples: Beef and leather, crude oil and gasoline, lumber and sawdust

4. Producer Expectations

  • Expected future price increase: Current supply may decrease (hold inventory for higher future prices)
  • Expected future price decrease: Current supply increases (sell now before prices fall)
  • Economic optimism: Firms invest more, increasing future supply capacity

5. Number of Firms

  • More firms enter: Market supply increases
  • Firms exit: Market supply decreases
  • Entry/exit often depends on profitability and barriers to entry

6. Government Policies

  • Subsidies: Lower production costs → Supply increases
  • Taxes: Increase production costs → Supply decreases
  • Regulations: Can increase or decrease supply depending on nature
  • Price controls: Can affect supply decisions

7. Natural Factors and Other Shocks

  • Weather: Droughts, floods, perfect conditions affect agricultural supply
  • Natural disasters: Earthquakes, hurricanes reduce supply
  • Discoveries: New resource deposits increase supply

Summary Table: Determinants of Supply

DeterminantChangeEffect on SupplyCurve Shift
Production CostsIncreaseDecreasesLeft
TechnologyImprovesIncreasesRight
Price of Substitute in ProductionIncreasesDecreases (for this good)Left
SubsidiesIntroduced/IncreasedIncreasesRight
Indirect TaxesIntroduced/IncreasedDecreasesLeft
Number of FirmsIncreasesIncreasesRight
Good Weather (Agriculture)OccursIncreasesRight

5. Market Equilibrium

Market Equilibrium: The point where quantity demanded equals quantity supplied. At this point, the market clears - there is no shortage or surplus, and the market is in balance.
Equilibrium Condition: \[ Q_d = Q_s \]

At equilibrium, we have:
  • Equilibrium Price (P*): The price at which Qd = Qs
  • Equilibrium Quantity (Q*): The quantity bought and sold at P*
📊 Equilibrium Diagram: The demand curve (D) and supply curve (S) intersect at point E (equilibrium). At this point, price is P* and quantity is Q*. The vertical axis shows Price (P), horizontal axis shows Quantity (Q).

Market Disequilibrium

When price is not at equilibrium, the market experiences either a shortage or surplus:

Surplus (Excess Supply):

Occurs when price is ABOVE equilibrium \( (P > P^*) \)

  • Quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded: \( Q_s > Q_d \)
  • Unsold inventory accumulates
  • Market pressure pushes price DOWN toward equilibrium
  • As price falls: Qd increases, Qs decreases → surplus eliminated
Shortage (Excess Demand):

Occurs when price is BELOW equilibrium \( (P < P^*) \)

  • Quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied: \( Q_d > Q_s \)
  • Consumers cannot buy all they want
  • Market pressure pushes price UP toward equilibrium
  • As price rises: Qd decreases, Qs increases → shortage eliminated

Changes in Equilibrium

Equilibrium price and quantity change when demand or supply shifts:

ChangeEffect on P*Effect on Q*Example
Demand Increases (D shifts right)IncreasesIncreasesRising incomes increase demand for cars
Demand Decreases (D shifts left)DecreasesDecreasesHealth warnings reduce demand for cigarettes
Supply Increases (S shifts right)DecreasesIncreasesTechnology improves, lowering costs
Supply Decreases (S shifts left)IncreasesDecreasesBad weather reduces crop supply
Numerical Example:
Market for smartphones:

Demand: \( Q_d = 100 - 2P \)
Supply: \( Q_s = 20 + 3P \)

At equilibrium: \( Q_d = Q_s \)
\( 100 - 2P = 20 + 3P \)
\( 80 = 5P \)
\( P^* = 16 \)

Substitute back: \( Q^* = 100 - 2(16) = 68 \)

Equilibrium: Price = $16, Quantity = 68 units

Simultaneous Shifts

When both demand and supply shift simultaneously, the effects on equilibrium depend on the relative magnitudes:

  • Both increase: Q* definitely increases; P* depends on which shift is larger
  • Both decrease: Q* definitely decreases; P* depends on which shift is larger
  • Demand increases, Supply decreases: P* definitely increases; Q* depends on which shift is larger
  • Demand decreases, Supply increases: P* definitely decreases; Q* depends on which shift is larger

6. The Price Mechanism

Price Mechanism: The process by which prices adjust through supply and demand forces to allocate resources efficiently in a market economy. It serves as an automatic system for coordinating economic decisions without central planning.

Three Functions of the Price Mechanism

1. Signaling Function

Prices communicate information to economic agents:

  • Rising prices signal scarcity/increasing demand → producers increase supply, consumers reduce demand
  • Falling prices signal abundance/decreasing demand → producers reduce supply, consumers increase demand
  • Prices convey information about relative scarcity and consumer preferences

Example: Rising oil prices signal scarcity, encouraging exploration, alternative energy development, and conservation.

2. Incentive Function

Prices motivate economic agents to respond:

  • High prices incentivize producers to increase supply and allocate more resources to that good
  • Low prices incentivize consumers to buy more and producers to switch resources to more profitable goods
  • Profit opportunities direct resources to their most valued uses

Example: High profits in smartphone industry incentivize tech companies to invest in research and production.

3. Rationing Function

Prices allocate scarce goods among competing uses:

  • When demand exceeds supply, rising prices ration goods to those willing and able to pay
  • Prevents shortages without government intervention
  • Resources flow to highest-value uses (those willing to pay most)

Example: During fuel shortages, higher prices ration gasoline to those who value it most, preventing queues and complete depletion.

Advantages of the Price Mechanism

  • Efficiency: Resources automatically flow to highest-value uses
  • Decentralization: No need for central planning or coordination
  • Flexibility: Quickly responds to changing conditions
  • Information: Prices aggregate millions of individual decisions
  • Innovation: Profit motive drives technological advancement

Limitations of the Price Mechanism

  • Market Failures: Externalities, public goods, information asymmetries
  • Inequality: Rationing by price favors the wealthy
  • Merit/Demerit Goods: Market may under/overprovide socially important goods
  • Monopoly Power: Firms may manipulate prices
  • Lack of Equity: Market outcomes may be socially undesirable

7. Allocative Efficiency

Allocative Efficiency: Occurs when resources are distributed in a way that maximizes social welfare. Production is allocated according to consumer preferences, and no reallocation can make anyone better off without making someone worse off (Pareto efficiency).

Condition for Allocative Efficiency

Allocative Efficiency is achieved when: \[ \text{Marginal Social Benefit (MSB)} = \text{Marginal Social Cost (MSC)} \]

In perfectly competitive markets: \[ \text{Price} = \text{Marginal Cost (MC)} \]

Or equivalently: \[ \text{Consumer Surplus} + \text{Producer Surplus is maximized} \]

Understanding Allocative Efficiency

At the market equilibrium in a competitive market:

  • Marginal Benefit = Price: Consumers' willingness to pay for the last unit equals the market price
  • Marginal Cost = Price: Producers' cost of supplying the last unit equals the market price
  • Therefore: MB = MC → Allocative efficiency achieved

Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus

Consumer Surplus: The difference between what consumers are willing to pay (shown by demand curve) and what they actually pay (market price). Represents consumer benefit from trade.

Graphically: Area below demand curve and above equilibrium price \[ CS = \frac{1}{2} \times (P_{\text{max}} - P^*) \times Q^* \]
Producer Surplus: The difference between the price producers receive (market price) and the minimum price they're willing to accept (shown by supply curve). Represents producer benefit from trade.

Graphically: Area above supply curve and below equilibrium price \[ PS = \frac{1}{2} \times (P^* - P_{\text{min}}) \times Q^* \]
Total Economic Surplus = Consumer Surplus + Producer Surplus

Allocative efficiency is achieved when total economic surplus is maximized. This occurs at competitive market equilibrium where supply equals demand.

Why Market Equilibrium Achieves Allocative Efficiency

Logic of Efficiency at Equilibrium:

If Q < Q*:
  • For units between current Q and Q*, consumers' willingness to pay (demand) exceeds production cost (supply)
  • Society benefits from producing more → current situation is inefficient
  • Both consumers and producers gain from additional trade

If Q > Q*:
  • For units beyond Q*, production cost exceeds consumers' willingness to pay
  • Resources are wasted producing unwanted goods → inefficient
  • Society would be better off reducing production

At Q = Q*:
  • No further gains from trade possible
  • All mutually beneficial exchanges have occurred
  • Resources are allocated optimally

Allocative Inefficiency: Deadweight Loss

Deadweight Loss (DWL): The loss of economic surplus (consumer + producer surplus) that occurs when market equilibrium is not achieved. It represents the value of foregone beneficial transactions.

Deadweight loss occurs when:

  • Price controls: Price ceilings or floors prevent equilibrium
  • Taxes: Create wedge between price paid by consumers and received by producers
  • Subsidies: Encourage overproduction beyond efficient level
  • Quotas: Restrict quantity below efficient level
  • Monopoly: Restricts output to raise prices
  • Externalities: MSB ≠ MPB or MSC ≠ MPC

Numerical Example: Consumer and Producer Surplus

Market Data:
Demand: \( P = 50 - 2Q \)
Supply: \( P = 10 + Q \)

Step 1: Find Equilibrium
\( 50 - 2Q = 10 + Q \)
\( 40 = 3Q \)
\( Q^* = 13.33 \) units
\( P^* = 10 + 13.33 = 23.33 \)

Step 2: Calculate Consumer Surplus
Maximum willingness to pay (when Q=0): P = 50
\( CS = \frac{1}{2} \times (50 - 23.33) \times 13.33 = 177.78 \)

Step 3: Calculate Producer Surplus
Minimum acceptable price (when Q=0): P = 10
\( PS = \frac{1}{2} \times (23.33 - 10) \times 13.33 = 88.89 \)

Step 4: Total Economic Surplus
\( \text{Total Surplus} = CS + PS = 177.78 + 88.89 = 266.67 \)

8. Real-World Applications

Application 1: COVID-19 Pandemic Effects

Hand Sanitizer Market (Early 2020):
  • Demand shift: Pandemic fears → massive demand increase (D shifts right)
  • Supply constraints: Production couldn't immediately expand
  • Result: Severe shortages, price spikes, rationing
  • Price mechanism: High prices incentivized production expansion, new entrants
  • Long-run: Supply caught up, prices normalized

Application 2: Electric Vehicle Market

Factors Increasing Demand:
  • Environmental concerns (tastes/preferences)
  • Government subsidies (reduces effective price)
  • Rising gasoline prices (substitute)
  • Improved technology (expectations)

Factors Increasing Supply:
  • Battery technology improvements
  • Economies of scale
  • More manufacturers entering market

Result: Rapid market growth with both D and S shifting right

Application 3: Housing Market

Shortage Scenario:
  • Demand factors: Population growth, low interest rates, investment demand
  • Supply constraints: Limited land, zoning regulations, construction time
  • Result: D increases faster than S → rising prices, affordability crisis
  • Allocative efficiency: High prices signal need for more housing, but supply response is slow

9. IB Economics Exam Skills

Drawing Diagrams (Essential for IB Exams):
  1. Always label axes: Price (P) vertical, Quantity (Q) horizontal
  2. Label curves: D for demand, S for supply
  3. Mark equilibrium: Point E where D and S intersect
  4. Show changes: Use D1→D2 or S1→S2 for shifts
  5. Indicate new equilibrium: E1→E2 with new P* and Q*
  6. Use arrows: Show direction of shifts and price/quantity changes
Common Exam Questions:
  • Explain: Use chain reasoning (cause → effect → consequence)
  • Analyze: Use diagrams + explain mechanism
  • Evaluate: Consider multiple stakeholders, short-run vs. long-run, assumptions
  • Calculate: Practice equilibrium and surplus calculations

Sample Exam Questions

Question 1: Using a diagram, explain how a government subsidy to electric vehicle manufacturers would affect the market equilibrium. [4 marks]

Answer Structure:
  • Subsidy reduces production costs for manufacturers
  • Supply increases (S shifts right from S1 to S2)
  • At original price, quantity supplied > quantity demanded
  • Surplus puts downward pressure on price
  • New equilibrium: lower price (P1→P2), higher quantity (Q1→Q2)
  • Diagram showing S shift right, E1→E2, with P↓ and Q↑
Question 2: Explain why market equilibrium represents allocative efficiency. [4 marks]

Answer Structure:
  • At equilibrium, marginal social benefit (demand) = marginal social cost (supply)
  • All mutually beneficial trades have occurred
  • Consumer and producer surplus are maximized
  • Resources are allocated to their highest-value uses
  • No reallocation can improve overall welfare without making someone worse off
Question 3: Using a diagram, analyze the effects of a major drought on the wheat market. [6 marks]

Answer Structure:
  • Drought is a negative supply shock
  • Reduces crop yields → supply decreases (S shifts left)
  • At original price, Qd > Qs (shortage)
  • Shortage creates upward pressure on price
  • Price rises, reducing Qd and increasing Qs along new curve
  • New equilibrium: higher price (P↑), lower quantity (Q↓)
  • Consequences: Consumers pay more and buy less; producers may earn higher/lower revenue depending on elasticity; food security concerns
  • Diagram essential with S shift left, shortage indicated, E1→E2

10. Key Formulas Reference

Equilibrium: \( Q_d = Q_s \)

Consumer Surplus: \( CS = \frac{1}{2} \times (P_{\max} - P^*) \times Q^* \)

Producer Surplus: \( PS = \frac{1}{2} \times (P^* - P_{\min}) \times Q^* \)

Total Economic Surplus: \( TS = CS + PS \)

Allocative Efficiency: \( MSB = MSC \) or \( P = MC \)

Conclusion

Demand and supply analysis forms the foundation of microeconomics. The interaction of these forces through the price mechanism determines market outcomes, allocates resources, and achieves allocative efficiency under ideal conditions. Understanding how markets work, how equilibrium is established and disrupted, and how efficiency is achieved or lost is essential for analyzing virtually every economic issue you'll encounter in IB Economics.

Master These Concepts:

  • The inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded (law of demand)
  • The positive relationship between price and quantity supplied (law of supply)
  • How non-price factors shift entire curves
  • How equilibrium is established through market forces
  • The three functions of the price mechanism
  • How competitive markets achieve allocative efficiency
  • How to calculate equilibrium, consumer surplus, and producer surplus
Exam Success Strategy:
  • Practice drawing accurate, labeled diagrams
  • Always distinguish between movements along curves vs. shifts of curves
  • Explain the mechanism: price change → shortage/surplus → adjustment → new equilibrium
  • Consider multiple perspectives: consumers, producers, government, society
  • Work through numerical examples to master calculations
  • Connect theory to real-world examples for deeper understanding
Shares: